October 8, 2024

Economix Blog: Yes, Even Young College Graduates Have Low Unemployment

CATHERINE RAMPELL

CATHERINE RAMPELL

Dollars to doughnuts.

I’ve written recently about the job prospects for college graduates versus those without bachelor’s degrees, noting that the unemployment rate for college graduates is about half that for workers with no more than a high school diploma (3.7 percent versus 8.1 percent as of January). Several readers wrote me to take issue with the fact that I was looking at the whole universe of workers with these credentials, rather than just the recently graduated. Perhaps college graduates from generations past are more protected than those just entering the work force, they wrote, and it is misleading to say that young graduates are equally secure.

It is true that young workers have higher unemployment rates than their older counterparts, at just about all levels of education. A recent report published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics on the job prospects of new college graduates, for example, found that as of October 2011, the graduates of the class of 2011 had an unemployment rate of 14 percent.

But that number refers to joblessness just a few months after graduation. If you look at all recent college graduates in their 20s, the unemployment rate drops sharply. It is especially impressive when compared with the jobless rate for all high school graduates in the same age group.

Sources: October School Enrollment Supplement, Current Population Survey, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Thomas Luke Spreen. Sources: October School Enrollment Supplement, Current Population Survey, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Thomas Luke Spreen.

As you can see, the unemployment rate for people in their 20s with college degrees or more education was 5.7 percent (for those whose highest credential was no more than a bachelor’s, the number was 5.8 percent). For those with only a high school diploma or G.E.D., it was more than twice as high, at 16.2 percent.

Here are comparable numbers for the employment-population ratio, or the share of people within each population who have a job (as opposed to being unemployed or not looking for work at all).

Sources: October School Enrollment Supplement, Current Population Survey, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Thomas Luke Spreen. Sources: October School Enrollment Supplement, Current Population Survey, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Thomas Luke Spreen.

The data are from Thomas Luke Spreen, who wrote the Labor Department report mentioned above. His numbers are culled from the 2011 October School Enrollment Supplement, an annual supplement to the Current Population Survey. (The Bureau of Labor Statistics’ public data on unemployment by educational attainment usually covers all workers 25 or older only, rather than narrower or younger ranges of workers.)

Of course, many of those college-educated 20-somethings are getting jobs that don’t really require college-level skills. But at least they’re finding work, unlike their less-educated peers. And as the economy continues to improve, those recent college graduates will be better situated to find promotions to jobs that do use their higher skills and pay better wages.

Article source: http://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/03/05/yes-even-young-college-graduates-have-low-unemployment/?partner=rss&emc=rss

Today’s Economist: Uwe E. Reinhardt: From Physician Glut to Physician Shortage

DESCRIPTION

Uwe E. Reinhardt is an economics professor at Princeton. He has some financial interests in the health care field.

In my most recent post, I made light of the argument that the Affordable Care Act would lead to a major shortage of physicians in this country. I was unpersuaded in part because the newly insured are likely to present only a marginal added demand for physician services. More important, I am not sure what we mean by “physician shortage.”

Today’s Economist

Perspectives from expert contributors.

Forecasters looking at the health work force have never reached a consensus on the ideal physician-population ratio for this country.

Indeed, widespread worries over a looming physician shortage are a relatively new phenomenon. They come at the time when experts are also lamenting an “epidemic of overtreatment” of patients, said to cost America $210 billion a year.

Throughout the 1980s, however, and until the late 1990s, the dominant narrative among experts on the American health work force was that, with the exception of primary care physicians, the United States faced a large overall future physician surplus. There were only a few demurrals from that dominant narrative.

The problem is that forecasting the future supply of and demand for any type of health professional is a highly complex and nuanced enterprise with wide margins of error (see, for example, Figures 9-1 and 9-6 in my 1991 paper).

Crucial in such forecasts is the assumption one makes about the average annual physician productivity in future years. That variable depends chiefly on two factors: the number of hours per year that physicians typically devote to patient care, and the degree to which physicians delegate to others tasks for which an M.D. degree is not required – for example, administrative tasks to clerks or business managers and certain medical tasks to physician assistants or nurse practitioners trained to perform tasks now performed by physicians.

How crucial that assumption is can be inferred from a once highly influential paper written in 1994 by Jonathan Weiner, a Johns Hopkins University health services researcher. In that study, Professor Weiner sought to estimate the impact of the then-impending Clinton health reform on the country’s future work force situation.

Professor Weiner noted that, in 1992, well-managed, clinically integrated, staff- or group-model health maintenance organizations that were compensated by prepaid capitation (an annual lump-sum fee per patient) required an average of only about 120 or so physicians per 100,000 enrollees, while the overall ratio of patient-care physician per 100,000 population in the United States was as high as 180 (about 220 in 2011; see Table 2 in this publication).

It appeared that the H.M.O. had pushed task delegation to nonphysician personnel further than had the rest of the health system. Furthermore, H.M.O.’s freed clinicians substantially from many administrative chores that physicians elsewhere must perform. Such H.M.O.’s, incidentally, would be the ideal form of the accountable care organizations called for in the Affordable Care Act of 2010.

Assuming, when he made the forecast in 1994, that as a result of the Clinton health reform some 40 to 60 percent of the United States population would be enrolled in such H.M.O.’s by 2000, Professor Weiner projected that the demand for and supply of primary care physicians would be more or less in balance in 2000, but that the supply of specialists would exceed the demand for them by more than 60 percent (a projected surplus of 165,000 physicians).

This prospect – widely accepted at the time — subsequently led the prestigious Council of Graduate Medical Education to recommend in its report of 1996 that “that the number of physicians entering residency be reduced from 140 percent to 110 percent of the number of graduates of allopathic and osteopathic medical schools in the United States in 1993.”

And why were health policy makers and work force specialists so worried at the time about an impending physician surplus? Did not standard economic theory predict that an imminent surplus would drastically drive down physician fees – particularly specialists’ fees — and thus make health care more affordable and accessible?

The problem is that this theory has found little empirical support in the data, in part because third-party payment intervenes. Furthermore, there has always been a strong belief, especially among policy makers, that modern medical practice, when coupled with third-party payment, is subject to an analogue of Parkinson’s Law. It is named after the British historian Cyril Northcote Parkinson (1909-93), who promulgated the law more or less in jest in 1955, then with regard to the British civil service.

According to Parkinson’s Law, “work will expand to fill the time available for its completion.” In medicine, its manifestation is feared to be the overtreatment of patients – sometimes harmful – even though individual physicians may sincerely believe that more care implies superior quality of treatment.

As the late economist Eli Ginzberg, an early pioneer in work force studies, noted as early as 1966: “Physicians are in a position to create their own demand.” He added that the effective use of physician manpower “depends in the first instance on a taut supply of physicians.”

Academic economists since that time have tied themselves into analytic knots over whether or not Ginzberg was right, in exercises reminiscent of medieval scholasticism. At the theoretical level, their models are mathematically elegant but lack predictive power. The data available at the empirical level does not allow economists to distinguish between health care actively demanded by patients and health care passively accepted on the doctor’s recommendation, nor between services prescribed by doctors in good conscience and those rendered mainly to shore up doctors’ incomes.

As on so many other areas of the real world, the views of economists on this matter cancel one another out.

Policy makers in the real world, however, seem to have no doubt that Parkinson’s Law applies to medical practice, as well. Consequently, they prefer paying physicians by annual capitation or bundled payments instead of “inflationary” fee-for-service, and they often seek to impose global budgets on physicians.

If Eli Ginzberg was right – and often he was – the suspected physician shortage now imputed by critics of the Affordable Care Act may actually drive our health system into more efficient medical practice. Step No. 1 in that direction, of course, would be to lighten the enormous administrative load now heaped by our health insurance system onto physicians devoted to rendering patient care.

Article source: http://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/08/31/from-physician-glut-to-physician-shortage/?partner=rss&emc=rss