November 22, 2024

Political Economy: How Europe Can Muddle Through Its Crisis

Three years on, debate still rages over what is to blame for the euro crisis and what to do about it. Meanwhile, large parts of the euro zone are in a deep recession, and the talents of a generation of young people are being wasted.

In looking at what went wrong, some point to the profligacy of borrowers, while others stress the design flaws in the system. Yet others pin the blame on how the crisis has been managed. There are still others who think that the euro zone is a victim of a credit crunch that began in the United States.

There is some truth in all those explanations. While the credit crunch did set off the crisis, it exposed a host of problems that had been masked by a decade of easy growth. Peripheral countries had grown uncompetitive as a result of rising wages. Often there was corruption and excessive debt, while anti-competitive practices that suited vested interests kept productivity low. Almost everywhere, governments ran unsustainably generous welfare states.

The crisis has also been managed appallingly. The zone took two years to let Greece restructure its debts. In the meantime, the banks in France, Germany and other countries that had financed Athens’s profligacy were able to get much of their money out of the country. If the banks had been hit early, their governments would have had to bail them out. The discussion would then have been as much about foolish lenders as about lazy borrowers.

Among the other mistakes were the failure to clean up the zone’s zombie banks and the fact that both fiscal and monetary policy were too tight. But troubled countries have also taken too long to root out vested interests and restore competitiveness.

Meanwhile, the two most popular solutions to the crisis are not really solutions at all. Euro skeptics want to break up the single currency. While the euro should not have been created when it was, the transitional economic and political costs of abandoning it would be enormous.

Euro enthusiasts, by contrast, pin their hopes on a full fiscal and political union to complement the monetary union. This is pie in the sky. Neither national politicians nor the people are willing to see much more power centralized in Brussels. There is good reason for that, too: The European Union is remote and only loosely accountable.

So what is the way forward? The answer is a muddle-through consisting of small doses of looser monetary and fiscal policy as well as a bit more integration, combined with large doses of change on both national and supranational levels.

To some extent, that is already happening. Only last week, the European Central Bank said it expected to keep its key interest rates at present or lower levels for an extended period. Given that the U.S. Federal Reserve is simultaneously indicating that it will tighten monetary policy as the U.S. economy continues to strengthen, the euro fell a bit versus the dollar. Further depreciation seems likely — something that would take the edge off the euro zone recession.

The E.C.B. has scope to run a looser monetary policy because inflation is undershooting its target of just below 2 percent. But one should not exaggerate its room for maneuver.

Meanwhile, the European Commission has been easing up on the fiscal austerity it demands of nations. This year, it gave several governments an extra year to hit budget targets. Now it is saying that, in some cases, it will exclude investment spending from its deficit calculations for the purpose of deciding whether austerity is required. It should do the same for any money governments inject into their banks as part of the cleanup that is soon to get under way.

But, again, one should not exaggerate the scope for fiscal laxity. Many governments have unsustainable deficits or debts. They cannot put off the day of reckoning forever.

Finally, the euro zone has agreed to some fiscal integration. The main instrument is the €500 billion, or $640 billion, European Stability Mechanism. This can be used to bail out governments and, in the future, banks too. But it is a limited backstop that can only be used as a last resort.

As a result, the heavy lifting remains with national governments, which need to press on with overhauling their labor markets, product markets and welfare states to restore competitiveness and cut unemployment. That is as it should be, because those constitute the bulk of the underlying problems.

What about Germany and the other northern countries? Shouldn’t they do more to help their peripheral brethren? The answer is yes, sort of.

A popular idea is that Berlin should do more to lift its economy by running a loose fiscal policy or encouraging higher pay for workers. Whatever the merits of that idea, two other policies could have a more direct benefit for peripheral economies. First, the European Union should extend the common market to services — opening up, in particular, Germany’s closed market to exports from elsewhere. Second, the European Union needs to spend more to combat youth unemployment. The €6 billion that leaders pledged to spend on that at their recent summit is, frankly, pathetic.

Even with such a raft of policies, it is not certain the euro zone can get out of its funk before the people rebel. But this is the probably the best game in town.

Hugo Dixon is editor at large of Reuters News.

Article source: http://www.nytimes.com/2013/07/08/business/global/08iht-dixon08.html?partner=rss&emc=rss

Economix Blog: Unemployed, and Wanting to Be Younger

Just ahead of the monthly jobs report on Friday, the Heldrich Center for Workforce Development has released its latest update on the wave of unemployed workers it has been following for two years now.

CATHERINE RAMPELL

CATHERINE RAMPELL

Dollars to doughnuts.

The most recent report has a number of interesting findings, but particularly striking were the open-ended responses to the question, “What is the one thing you think would help the most in getting you a new job?”

Many of the responses were filled with a sense of hopelessness, or at the very least a sense of resignation. Two of the respondents said they needed “a miracle.”

Perhaps most worrisome, dozens said that the only thing that could help them was “being younger.” Fears of age discrimination have frequently come up in my conversations with unemployed workers as well, given that older workers have the longest spells of joblessness (though there are other possible explanations for this).

Here’s a word cloud of the responses showing how prevalent age-related answers were:

DESCRIPTIONSource: John J. Heldrich Center for Workforce Development. Image created using Wordle.net.

Article source: http://feeds.nytimes.com/click.phdo?i=5f575872d81e710299aaceddd2621756

Trade in Pork Bellies Comes to an End, but the Lore Lives

CHICAGO — This city’s market for the pork belly, a commodity nearly everyone seemed to have heard of but only a small, close-knit fraternity truly understood, is no more.

When the Chicago Mercantile Exchange announced the other day that pork belly futures would no longer be traded, it was hardly a shock. Trades had shrunk to almost nothing. Volatility was too much. The frozen bellies, used to make bacon, were, in the view of some, losing relevance.

Still, the demise of the futures means something else is really gone now, too — a unique belly culture and its hard-charging, daring cast of characters who, decades ago, made their fortunes in the high pressure of the belly pit.

“It was a club,” said Gary Wilhelmi, who arrived at the Chicago Mercantile Exchange as a markets reporter not long after pork bellies helped pioneer the exchange’s livestock futures markets in 1961. “If you were new, you could come to the trading floor, and you could come to the belly pit. But they wouldn’t trade with you.”

There was the balding trader whose wig was seen as a gauge of the market’s volatility; on the craziest days, the wig’s part ran ear to ear, Mr. Wilhelmi recalled. There was the analyst who died right there. “Bellies killed him,” Mr. Wilhelmi said. And there was the veteran trader who once told Mr. Wilhelmi — who was, at the time, trying to analyze a trading report on pork bellies — not to bother. “The bellies,” the trader told him, “are what we say they are.”

Pork bellies have long held a puzzling mystique to the public. Experts in the field offer a range of sometimes conflicting explanations: everybody likes bacon; the word “belly” sounds funny; no one actually knows what a pork belly is. Whatever the reason, pork bellies pop up in an inordinate number of references in magazines, popular culture and movies, like “Trading Places,” the 1983 film in which Eddie Murphy’s character used pork bellies to explain, in unforgettably bare terms, how a market works.

To hear many who frequented the Chicago Mercantile Exchange in the early 1960s tell it, the trading of pork belly futures seemed to open up a whole new set of possibilities — other livestock, for instance — for the exchange. “The bellies are gone,” said Gary Truitt, the president of Hoosier Ag Today. “But they really did make a contribution.”

Way back, pork belly futures made sense. The bellies were frozen and set aside, then used to make bacon during the summers when the demand for it (think bacon, lettuce and tomato sandwiches) rose. But the pork belly landscape has shifted, said Shane Ellis, a livestock economist at Iowa State University. With bacon accompanying salads, hamburgers, even chocolate, it is on call all year now, removing some of the demand for frozen bellies.

For many here, the announcement by the Chicago Mercantile Exchange in July that no further such trades would be made was merely acknowledging the inevitable. Some said it was high time. Past time, in the view of some, who had worried that the ups and downs of trading were too risky when almost no trades at all were being made. It was hard to imagine next to the memories of the old belly pit, where you had to really watch out, Mr. Truitt said, or you would “get your clock cleaned.”

Article source: http://feeds.nytimes.com/click.phdo?i=0e63982bf6e84ffb8a8ba51e4cd5fa5f

Economix: The Concentrated Pain of Job Loss

DAVID LEONHARDT

DAVID LEONHARDT

Thoughts on the economic scene.

I wanted to add one other explanation — to those Catherine Rampell cited, in her much-discussed Sunday article — for why unemployment has not become a larger political issue. Given how high unemployment is, there are surprisingly few people who have experienced unemployment in the last couple of years. This is the flip side of the historically high average length of the unemployment: joblessness is concentrated among a subset of the population, rather than affecting a larger group of people for shorter periods of time.

One set of numbers from the Bureau of Labor Statistics makes the case. In 1982, the unemployment rate averaged between 9 and 10 percent — and fully 22 percent of the labor force experienced unemployment at some point during the year. In 2009 (the most recent year of data), the unemployment rate also averaged between 9 and 10 percent, but only (or maybe “only”) 16.4 percent of the labor force experienced unemployment at some point during the year.

Just as surprising, the share of the labor force that experienced unemployment in 2009 was lower than in the early 1960s, when the unemployment rate was generally below 7 percent. Why? Among other things, temporary layoffs were more common in the past than today.

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

To be sure, the concentrated nature of unemployment may not be as important as the other big explanations cited in the Sunday article. But the difference is still striking: In 1982, the share of people who experienced unemployment was more than one-third larger than in 2009.

I discussed the phenomenon in more detail in two previous columns, including one in 2009:

Instead of doing lots of firing and some hiring, many companies have done only some firing and virtually no hiring, the statistics show. And that isn’t all bad.

Try thinking of it this way: All of the unemployed people in the country are gathered in a huge gymnasium that’s been turned into a job search center. The fact that this recession is the worst in a generation means that there are many, many people in the gym. The fact that the economy is churning so slowly means that there is not much traffic into and out of the gym.

If you’re inside, you will have a hard time getting out. Yet if you’re lucky enough to be outside the gym, you will probably be able to stay there. The consequences of a job loss are terribly high, but — given that the unemployment rate is almost 10 percent — the odds of job loss are surprisingly low.

The reasons for the slow churn are obviously complex. The baby boomers are moving out of the ages at which people typically start businesses. The economy has shifted away from sectors, like manufacturing, in which temporary layoffs are common. Educational gains have slowed, which affects innovation. And the federal government was not willing, at least until recently, to make the kind of investments that spurred entrepreneurship in the past — building the highway system, supporting scientific research, creating the Pentagon computer network that turned into the Internet.

But whatever the causes, the effects of the slow churn are clear: the pain of this recession has been concentrated.

Article source: http://feeds.nytimes.com/click.phdo?i=152c29313cdaf89f7033bc85207abfdf