November 17, 2024

Today’s Economist: Nancy Folbre: Our Carbon, Our Climate, Our Cash

Nancy Folbre, economist at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst.

Nancy Folbre is an economics professor at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst. She recently edited and contributed to “For Love and Money: Care Provision in the United States.

We all buy stuff that generates carbon dioxide emissions and threatens the stability of our climate. We don’t directly pay the resulting costs, which are postponed to a vague and indefinite future in which none of us can be held individually accountable for a devastating increase in the level and variability of average global temperatures.

Today’s Economist

Perspectives from expert contributors.

A tax on carbon consumption could help solve the problem, bringing the prices of carbon-intensive goods and services into closer alignment with their true costs and discouraging us all from buying more of them.

We would be hard hit by a sudden shift in relative prices, and some of us are especially vulnerable to an increase in energy costs. However, we could use carbon tax revenues to help compensate for the shock – offering everyone a rebate-like dividend to buffer reductions in purchasing power and encouraging ourselves to invest in technologies that reduce our carbon footprint.

A new Climate Protection Act introduced by Senators Bernard Sanders, the independent from Vermont, and Barbara Boxer, Democrat of California, proposes such a tax. About 60 percent of the revenues would be returned directly to consumers, 25 percent allotted to deficit reduction and 15 percent devoted to investments in renewable energy.

The bill’s sponsors aim to win the support of the American people rather than influential industry lobbying groups. Is this aim a strength or a weakness? The way you answer this question depends on who you think will throw the most weight behind climate-change legislation. It also depends on who you think “owns” our atmosphere and who you believe should get compensated when it is compromised.

Support for some kind of fee on carbon consumption that would distribute revenues to offset adjustment costs has been gaining steam for several years. In a commentary published in The New York Times in 2009, James Hansen, one of the world’s most respected climate scientists, asserted that the better-known cap-and trade approach, allowing companies to buy and sell permits to emit pollutants, had proved both ineffective and vulnerable to corruption.

He emphasized that a dividend-based approach would give consumers a stronger incentive to change their behavior and give voters a stronger incentive to support significant regulation.

Dr. Hansen’s logic lent support to a bill introduced in Congress by Senators Maria Cantwell, Democrat of Washington, and Susan Collins, Republican of Maine, proposing a cap on carbon emissions that would lead to price increases counterbalanced by per-capita dividends for consumers. In an analysis of the likely impact of such a policy, James K. Boyce and Matthew E. Riddle, my colleagues at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst, found that about 70 percent of households – and a majority of households in every state in the country – would enjoy net cash benefits.

Evidence of political traction comes from a recent proposal from the California Public Utilities Commission incorporating a dividend-based approach. It calls for distribution of some revenues from the auction of carbon emission permits to industries to be distributed equally to every residential utility account. The commission noted that this policy “comports with the idea of common ownership of the atmosphere given that residential ratepayers will ultimately bear the increased costs.”

But the Cantwell-Collins bill was largely sidelined by a push to win bipartisan support from major industry groups to pass cap-and-trade legislation. This push proved unsuccessful, perhaps because major environmental groups pursued a classic Beltway strategy of extensive lobbying and negotiation over technical details of little interest to all but major industry players. In a detailed postmortem, the Harvard political scientist Theda Skocpol contends that this strategy made it easier for Republican opponents to sway recession-weary voters fearful of the negative economic impact of higher energy prices.

The tax-and-dividend approach, by contrast, appeals directly to voters as consumers, encouraging them to change their buying habits but subsidizing that change through progressive redistribution. It also gives them a stake in higher carbon-tax revenues – economic skin in the game.

Here’s the big question: whose economic skin is most important? As Professor Skocpol makes clear, environmental groups supported cap-and-trade because they believed energy industry support was vital for climate change legislation. Some economists, including Adele Morris in a paper published by the Hamilton Project, and Donald Marron at the Tax Policy Center, assert that revenues from a carbon tax should be used to significantly lower corporate tax rates. This proposal is obviously likely to win corporate support.

But the energy industry is dominated by companies with a big stake in fossil fuels, and effective corporate tax rates are already low by international standards. There is little evidence that large businesses are suffering from any shortfall of funds to invest. Quite the contrary – profits are way up because wages have been squeezed. If anything, global businesses seem to have too much idle cash.

A tax-and-dividend policy could increase consumer spending and increase demand for energy conservation and renewable energy technologies, improving the prospects for sustainable economic growth.

It might not save all our skins, but it would offer some valuable protection from the coming burn.

Article source: http://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/03/25/our-carbon-our-climate-our-cash/?partner=rss&emc=rss

DealBook: Macarthur Coal Accepts Increased Takeover Bid

An excavator loads coal at Macarthur Coal's Moorvale mine located about 466 miles northwest of Brisbane, Australia.Macarthur Coal, via ReutersAn excavator loads coal at Macarthur Coal’s Moorvale mine located about 466 miles northwest of Brisbane, Australia.

7:31 p.m. | Updated

Macarthur Coal, an Australian mining company that has been the subject of multiple takeover bids over the last year and a half, bowed on Tuesday to an improved offer from ArcelorMittal and Peabody Energy, valuing Macarthur at about 4.8 billion Australian dollars, or $5.2 billion.

The company, a specialist producer of pulverized coal that is sought after by steel makers, is one of the last remaining independent midsize mining operations in Australia and had long been considered an attractive acquisition target.

Rising raw material prices and a desire by resource companies and steelmakers to meet ravenous demand from China and other rapidly growing emerging economies have spurred consolidation in the sector in recent years. Macarthur, based in Brisbane, last year turned down two bids by rivals and a major asset swap plan with another company.

Last month, it spurned a new offer by ArcelorMittal and Peabody of 15.5 Australian dollars a share, prompting the two to take their bid directly to shareholders on Aug. 1. ArcelorMittal, with $78 billion in annual revenue, already holds a 16 percent stake in Macarthur.

At the time, Keith DeLacy, chairman of Macarthur, said the bid appeared to be an “opportunistic attempt” to acquire the mining company at a time of global economic volatility and regulatory uncertainty in Australia.

The country is considering imposing a carbon tax and a resource tax, both of which would affect the mining sector.

On Tuesday, Peabody Energy, based in St. Louis, and ArcelorMittal nudged up their joint offer by 3 percent, to 16 Australian dollars a share. The bidders are seeking at least 50.01 percent of the coal mining company. The new offer is 44 percent above the stock’s closing price on the day before the initial offer was announced.

“In the period since the initial offer, a number of parties have conducted due diligence,” Macarthur said in a statement on Tuesday, adding that the company’s board was recommending the raised bid to Macarthur shareholders. “Although it remains possible that a superior proposal might be made, none have emerged to date and there can be no assurances that any will emerge.”

Investors seemed to concur. Macarthur shares closed at 15.86 Australian dollars on Tuesday, indicating that the market was not betting a higher bid would materialize.

“This is a major step forward in our acquisition process,” Gregory H. Boyce, the Peabody chairman and chief executive, said in a statement.

The offer, which is subject to regulatory approval, is one of the largest so far this year in the mining sector, which has been a hotbed of deal-making activity.

Yanzhou Coal Mining, a Chinese company, bought Felix Resources for 3.5 billion Australian dollars in 2009, for example, while Minmetals bought most of the assets of the Australian mining company Oz Minerals. Also in 2009, Hunan Valin Iron and Steel Group took a 16.5 percent stake in the Fortescue Metals Group, an Australian iron ore mining company.

Article source: http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2011/08/30/macarthur-bows-to-raised-peabody-and-arcelor-bid/?partner=rss&emc=rss